Econometrics Lesson 1 2023
Econometrics Lesson 1 2023
an important part of econometrics, the scope of econometrics is much broader, as can be seen
Econometrics, the result of a certain outlook on the role of economics, consists of the application
of mathematical statistics to economic data to lend empirical support to the models constructed
Econometrics may be defined as the quantitative analysis of actual economic phenomena based
inference
Econometrics may be defined as the social science in which the tools of economic theory,
mathematics, and statistical inference are applied to the analysis of economic phenomena.
The art of the econometrician consists in finding the set of assumptions that are both sufficiently
specific and sufficiently realistic to allow him to take the best possible advantage of the data
available to him.
Econometricians are a positive help in trying to dispel the poor public image of economics
(quantitative or otherwise) as a subject in which empty boxes are opened by assuming the
existence of can-openers to reveal contents which any ten economists will interpret in 11 ways.
The method of econometric research aims, essentially, at a conjunction of economic theory and
actual measurements, using the theory and technique of statistical inference as a bridge pier.
WHY A SEPARATE DISCIPLINE?
mathematical economics, economic statistics, and mathematical statistics. Yet the subject
deserves to be studied in its own right for the following reasons. Economic theory makes
statements or hypotheses that are mostly qualitative in nature. For example, microeconomic
theory states that, other things remaining the same, a reduction in the price of a commodity is
Thus, economic theory postulates a negative or inverse relationship between the price and
quantity demanded of a commodity. But the theory itself does not provide any numerical
measure of the relationship between the two; that is, it does not tell by how much the quantity
will go up or down as a result of a certain change in the price of the commodity. It is the job of
the econometrician to provide such numerical estimates. Stated differently, econometrics gives
theory. As we shall see, the econometrician often uses the mathematical equations proposed by
the mathematical economist but puts these equations in such a form that they lend themselves to
empirical testing. And this conversion of mathematical into econometric equations requires a
Economic statistics is mainly concerned with collecting, processing, and presenting economic
data in the form of charts and tables. These are the jobs of the economic statistician. It is he or
she who is primarily responsible for collecting data on gross national product (GNP),
employment, unemployment, prices, etc. The data thus collected constitute the raw data for
econometric work. But the economic statistician does not go any further, not being concerned
with using the collected data to test economic theories. Of course, one who does that becomes an
econometrician.
Although mathematical statistics provides many tools used in the trade, the econometrician often
needs special methods in view of the unique nature of most economic data, namely, that the data
are not generated as the result of a controlled experiment. The econometrician, like the
observes:
In econometrics the modeler is often faced with observational as opposed to experimental data.
This has two important implications for empirical modeling in econometrics. First, the modeler
is required to master very different skills than those needed for analyzing experimental data. . . .
Second, the separation of the data collector and the data analyst requires the modeler to
familiarize himself/herself thoroughly with the nature and structure of data in question.
METHODOLOGY OF ECONOMETRICS
How do econometricians proceed in their analysis of an economic problem? That is, what is their
present here the traditional or classical methodology, which still dominates empirical research in
Broadly speaking, traditional econometric methodology proceeds along the following lines:
1. Statement of theory or hypothesis.
2. Specification of the mathematical model of the theory
3. Specification of the statistical, or econometric, model
4. Obtaining the data
5. Estimation of the parameters of the econometric model
6. Hypothesis testing
7. Forecasting or prediction
8. Using the model for control or policy purposes.
To illustrate the preceding steps, let us consider the well-known Keynesian theory of
consumption
Keynes stated: The fundamental psychological law is that men [women] are disposed, as
a rule and on average, to increase their consumption as their income increases, but not as
In short, Keynes postulated that the marginal propensity to consume (MPC), the rate of
change of consumption for a unit (say, a dollar) change in income, is greater than zero but
less than 1.
did not specify the precise form of the functional relationship between the two. For
simplicity, a mathematical economist might suggest the following form of the Keynesian
consumption function:
Equation 1
where Y = consumption expenditure and X = income, and where β1 and β2, known as the
parameters of the model, are, respectively, the intercept and slope coefficients.
The slope coefficient β2 measures the MPC. Geometrically, Eq. (1) is as shown in Figure
I.1. This equation, which states that consumption, is lintionship between consumption
and income that is called the consumption function in economics. A model is simply a set
of mathematical equations. If the model has only one equation, as in the preceding
example, it is called a single-equation model, whereas if it has more than one equation, it
In Equation (1) the variable appearing on the left side of the equality sign is called the
dependent variable and the variable(s) on the right side are called the independent, or
variable.
model of the consumption function given in Equation (1) is of limited interest to the
econometrician, for it assumes that there is an exact or deterministic relationship between
consumption and income. But relationships between economic variables are generally
inexact. Thus, if we were to obtain data on consumption expenditure and disposable (i.e.,
after tax) income of a sample of, say, 500 American families and plot these data on a
graph paper with consumption expenditure on the vertical axis and disposable income on
the horizontal axis, we would not expect all 500 observations to lie exactly on the straight
line of Equation (1) because, in addition to income, other variables affect consumption
expenditure. For example, size of family, ages of the members in the family, family
To allow for the inexact relationships between economic variables, the econometrician
Equation (2)
where u, known as the disturbance, or error, term, is a random (stochastic) variable that
has well-defined probabilistic properties. The disturbance term u may well represent all
those factors that affect consumption but are not taken into account explicitly. Equation
regression model, which is the major concern of this book. The econometric consumption
the explanatory variable X (income) but that the relationship between the two is not
To estimate the econometric model given in Equation (2), that is, to obtain the numerical
values of β1 and β2, we need data. Although we will have more to say about the crucial
importance of data for economic analysis in the next chapter, for now let us look at the
(for the economy as a whole) personal consumption expenditure (PCE) and the X
variable is gross domestic product (GDP), a measure of aggregate income, both measured
in billions of 1992 dollars. Therefore, the data are in “real” terms; that is, they are
measured in constant (1992) prices. The data are plotted in Figure I.3 (cf. Figure I.2). For
Now that we have the data, our next task is to estimate the parameters of the consumption
function. The numerical estimates of the parameters give empirical content to the
discussed later. For now, note that the statistical technique of regression analysis is the
main tool used to obtain the estimates. Using this technique and the data given in Table
I.1, we obtain the following estimates of β1 and β2, namely, −184.08 and 0.7064. Thus,
Equation (3)
The hat on the Y indicates that it is an estimate. The estimated consumption function (i.e.,
As Figure I.3 shows, the regression line fits the data quite well in that the data points are
very close to the regression line. From this figure we see that for the period 1982–1996
the slope coefficient (i.e., the MPC) was about 0.70, suggesting that for the sample period
consumption and income is inexact; as is clear from Figure I.3; not all the data points lie
exactly on the regression line. In simple terms we can say that, according to our data, the
Hypothesis Testing
Assuming that the fitted model is a reasonably good approximation of reality, we have to
develop suitable criteria to find out whether the estimates obtained in, say, Eq. (I.3) are in
accord with the expectations of the theory that is being tested. According to “positive”
economists like Milton Friedman, a theory or hypothesis that is not verifiable by appeal
we found the MPC to be about 0.70. But before we accept this finding as confirmation of
below unity to convince us that this is not a chance occurrence or peculiarity of the
particular data we have used. In other words, is 0.70 statistically less than 1? If it is, it
Forecasting or Prediction
If the chosen model does not refute the hypothesis or theory under consideration, we may
use it to predict the future value(s) of the dependent, or forecast, variable Y on the basis
illustrate, suppose we want to predict the mean consumption expenditure for 1997. The
GDP value for 1997 was 7269.8 billion dollars. Putting this GDP figure on the right-hand
or about 4951 billion dollars. Thus, given the value of the GDP, the mean, or average,
forecast consumption expenditure is about 4951 billion dol lars. The actual value of the
consumption expenditure reported in 1997 was 4913.5 billion dollars. The estimated
model (I.3.3) thus overpredicted the actual consumption expenditure by about 37.82
billion dollars. We could say the forecast error is about 37.82 billion dollars, which is
about 0.76 percent of the actual GDP value for 1997. When we fully discuss the linear
regression model in subsequent chapters, we will try to find out if such an error is “small”
or “large.” But what is important for now is to note that such forecast errors are inevitable
given the statistical nature of our analysis. There is another use of the estimated model
(I.3.3). Suppose the Presi dent decides to propose a reduction in the income tax. What
will be the ef fect of such a policy on income and thereby on consumption expenditure
and ultimately on employment? Suppose that, as a result of the proposed policy change,
macroeconomic theory shows, the change in income following, say, a dollar’s worth of
as
If we use the MPC of 0.70 obtained in Equation (3), this multiplier becomes about M =
3.33. That is, an increase (decrease) of a dollar in investment will eventually lead to more
than a threefold increase (decrease) in income; note that it takes time for the multiplier to
work. The critical value in this computation is MPC, for the multiplier depends on it. And
this estimate of the MPC can be obtained from regression models such as Equation (3).
Thus, a quantitative estimate of MPC provides valuable information for policy purposes.
Knowing MPC, one can predict the future course of income, consumption expenditure,
Suppose we have the estimated consumption function given in Equation (3). Suppose
further the government believes that consumer expenditure of about 4900 (billions of
1992 dollars) will keep the unemployment rate at its current level of about 4.2 percent
(early 2000). What level of income will guarantee the target amount of consumption
expenditure? If the regression results given in Equation (3) seem reasonable, simple
which gives X = 7197, approximately. That is, an income level of about 7197 (billion)
dollars, given an MPC of about 0.70, will produce an expenditure of about 4900 billion
dollars. As these calculations suggest, an estimated model may be used for control, or
policy, purposes. By appropriate fiscal and monetary policy mix, the government can
manipulate the control variable X to produce the desired level of the target variable Y.
As the classificatory scheme in Figure I.5 suggests, econometrics may be divided into
category, one can approach the subject in the classical or Bayesian tradition. In this book
the emphasis is on the classical approach. For the Bayesian approach, the reader may
consult the references given at the end of the chapter. Theoretical econometrics is
on mathematical statistics. For example, one of the methods used extensively in this book
is least squares. Theoretical econometrics must spell out the assumptions of this method,
its properties, and what happens to these properties when one or more of the assumptions
of the method are not fulfilled. In applied econometrics we use the tools of theoretical
econometrics to study some special field(s) of economics and business, such as the
production function, investment function, demand and supply functions, portfolio theory,
etc. This book is concerned largely with the development of econometric methods, their
assumptions, their uses, their limitations. These methods are illustrated with examples
from various areas of economics and business. But this is not a book of applied
econometrics in the sense that it delves deeply into any particular field of economic
application.