Chapter 1
Chapter 1
and Economic Damages
Business Liability
and Economic Damages
Second Edition
Scott D. Gilbert
Business Liability and Economic Damages, Second Edition
Copyright © Business Expert Press, LLC, 2020.
10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1
Keywords
business dispute; business liability; economic damages; economic model;
insurance claim; lawsuit; personal injury; present value; risk; wrongful
death; antitrust
Contents
Preface to the First Edition......................................................................ix
Preface...................................................................................................xi
Chapter 1 Business Liability...............................................................1
Chapter 2 Economic Loss.................................................................17
Chapter 3 Compensation for Loss....................................................37
Chapter 4 Evidence of Loss...............................................................71
Chapter 5 Loss to Workers and Families.........................................107
Chapter 6 Antitrust and Harm to Competition..............................119
Afterword............................................................................................151
Glossary..............................................................................................153
Bibliography........................................................................................159
About the Author.................................................................................165
Index..................................................................................................167
Preface to the First Edition
Let’s be honest. There’s not a business anywhere that is without problems.
Business is complicated and imperfect. Every business everywhere is
staffed with imperfect human beings and exists by providing a product
or service to other imperfect human beings.
—Bob Parsons (Go Daddy founder)
Business Liability
Liability does apply with respect to the amount of the oil spill.
—Ken Salazar, U.S. Secretary of the Interior,
addressing the Gulf Oil Spill in 2010
Learning Objectives
1. Describe the concept and scope of business liability.
2. Summarize the effects of insurance and business organization
on liability.
3. Explain the role of courts, mediation, and arbitration in
addressing liability claims.
business contracts entail liabilities that are fairly easy to foresee, but not all.
Furthermore, the scope of business liability extends beyond contracts, and
the great reach of potential liability makes it even harder to foresee. This
book focuses on business liabilities whose consequences are relatively hard
to predict, but can nevertheless be identified and prepared for in some way.
Business liability comes from many directions, so many that a detailed
account of all possibilities is impossible. A business cannot foresee every
form of liability, but its managers and owners should develop an intuitive
understanding of liability by considering the business’s relationships with
society. It is not just desired relationships that might be listed in a business
plan, but actual ones.
To get a grip on the real scope of business liability, you have to think big,
have a big picture in mind, a big idea. One big idea discussed in this book
is the social contract. For a business owner or manager who wants to avoid a
business liability mistake, it is useful to take the view that businesses have li-
ability because they are bound by a social contract to avoid certain harms to
others. The social contract does not take the form of a tidy 5-page or 10-page
document that a business signs and sends to the government. It does not
necessarily stay the same over time, and may or may not ultimately be fair. It
does reflect and signify the body of laws and regulations that a business faces
and is colored by the economic, social, and political institutions of the day.
A social contract can serve as a theme or umbrella for myriad elements of
business liability—and so can serve as a conceptual model to simplify some
aspects of liability faced by business owners and managers. As a practical
matter, for the purposes of this book a social contract is an idea or framework
that serves to define and limit the rights and responsibilities of society’s members.1
1
The origins of the philosophical idea of social contract lie in the classical works of
Hobbes (1651), Rousseau (1762), Locke (1689), and others, with more recent con-
tributions by Rawls (1971) and Sen (2009). An essential point in this literature is
that people collectively enter into a social contract in order to get some benefits from
others, while giving up some personal liberties along the way. The existence of a social
contract, in these terms, seems obvious, but the existence of a grand, encompassing,
and comprehensible social contract is unclear, which sinks the idea that society might
actually be actively participating in it. As a practical matter, a social contract neces-
sitates an agreement among members of society, defining and limiting the rights and
duties of each. In the narrow focus of business liability, particularly in a given indus-
try, this specialized notion of social contract is intelligible and useful.
Business Liability 3
Business
Other
Public Government
businesses
not find work because the legal system had become weak and lawyers
were of little use, so he ran a convenience store instead at the University
of the Philippines. Matters have improved greatly since that time, but
weak legal institutions and corruption continue to be problems for law
in the developing world.2 In many countries, a business can bribe its way
out of many obligations to society. In America the bribe is less reliable, in
part because government officials are better paid and so less benefitted by
bribes economically and also because a centuries-old tradition of govern-
ment propriety still carries momentum—despite many lapses.
For a business manager pondering the scope of the company’s liability,
it is useful to develop an intuitive and informed sense of what is owed to
society, as if the company were bound by a social contract that could be
spelled out, at least in principle. This sense of obligation does not require
a knowledge of all U.S. laws—not even lawyers or judges have that. The
relevant social contract includes a set of rights and limitations on be-
havior that protect people from harm, and a basic understanding of the
legal scope of harm is a must. As noted in the Preface, the book you are
reading is no form of legal advice, but the economics of business liability
and damages is framed by the legal system, so a discussion of the legal
landscape is inevitable.
A good starting point for assessing business liability is to briefly detail
the six relationships shown in Figure 1.1. Loans and other business con-
tracts create business-to-business liability, but each business has custom-
ers and—like it or not—potential liability in their customer relationships.
Employees are owed paychecks but also owed fair and respectful treat-
ment, a form of liability shaped by the social contract between the em-
ployer and the employee. For businesses big enough so that their actions
are not one and the same as that of their owners, business owes its owners,
and so is liable to them. All businesses know about taxes—one sort of
debt owed to the government, and some end up with other ties to assets
that lie in the government’s reach, and so more liability. Furthermore,
2
The Philippines and many other relatively poor countries have relatively high levels of
corruption, while the United States and other relatively rich countries like Germany,
Japan, and Australia have relatively low levels of corruption. See, for example, the
Corruptions Perception Index 2014 available from Transparency International online.
Business Liability 5
Insurance
In this book we will be talking mostly about business liabilities that are
hard to anticipate; for example, product defects, which unlike debts and
interest payments, are hard to predict.
To deal with unexpected liabilities, an elegant solution is insurance—
a contract in which one party meets the obligations of another, under specific
conditions. Pay a premium and the nightmare of ruinous mistaken harm
6 BUSINESS LIABILITY AND ECONOMIC DAMAGES
Obligation
Business Society
Obligation
Insurer
and its insurer has an obligation to the insurer. It is easy to suppose in-
stead that the insurer assumes the business’s obligation. For example, in
routine car accidents a claim is usually made against a driver’s insurer and
not against the driver directly. This saves time and money, but the true
obligation lies with the party that caused harm. The less a business knows
about how this works, and the more it relies on an insurance company to
advise and guide it, the more money the insurance company makes and
the greater liability the business faces. Insurers do not want businesses to
read this book!
Insurance companies want to cultivate ongoing relationships with
most businesses they serve, but this goodwill dries up for customers who
become stand-out risks. Businesses that cause harm become less desirable
insurance customers, because they pose a greater perceived risk of future
harm. Stand-out risks are lemons to the insurer. For lemons, insurance
companies have no goodwill, and they will minimally service their poli-
cies. They may also drag out the process, with years of court proceedings
needed to settle a matter, and regardless of the damage, such proceed-
ings may diminish a business’s reputation. In states like New York, where
anyone can track almost every lawsuit’s progress online, and chat online
about it, dragged-out liability disputes carry a potentially huge reputation
cost for businesses.
Insurance policies are just business contracts—agreements that can
be breached. The insurer will try to avoid breach or risk the ire of regula-
tors. Deep pockets help, but some insurance companies still go belly up.
8 BUSINESS LIABILITY AND ECONOMIC DAMAGES
State governments know this and provide some backup insurance funds.
These create a possible economic problem of moral hazard—an exces-
sive shift of risk from one party to another, due to risk avoidance, by
which businesses underinsure with the confidence that the government
will pick up the remaining tab. But governments are onto that trick, and
woe to the insurer that thinks otherwise. Every business should, however,
be aware of any such backups, and should carefully study the financial
health and customer satisfaction of would-be insurers, before buying li-
ability insurance.
Business Forms
Business liability is a burden with the potential to cripple innovation and
economic growth. Mindful of this, the framers of America’s social con-
tract capped financial liability via the corporation. A potential customer
or service provider that does commerce with a corporation has limited
recourse if commerce goes bad, but the existence of corporations also
provides more economic opportunity and choice. The same idea applies
to other forms of limited liability business entities, including the limited
liability company (LLC), type S corporation, and limited liability part-
nership (LLP).
The existence of corporations demonstrates a sort of hands-off, or
laissez faire, approach of lawmakers to financial gain and loss. With this
hands-off approach, lawmakers concede that a full dose of liability in the
social contract would be toxic to the economy. But it is an uneasy conces-
sion, with limited scope. The corporation’s structure protects its owners
from losing their homes if a business deal fails, but does not absolve them
of responsibility for harms that the corporation may cause. Recalling the
diverse forms of liability shown in Figure 1.1, every corporation has li-
abilities that exceed its financial commitments. All these extra liabilities
can potentially pierce the corporate veil and pass through its owners, as
shown in Figure 1.3.
The prospect of the corporation’s owners bleeding cash from their
savings accounts, to cover corporate liabilities, may seem unfair. But
the threat of such pass-through liability protects society from having
every business formally pose itself as a corporation, or a bunch of
Business Liability 9
Corporation
Society
Owners
Whether or not they end up in court, all business liabilities are framed
by the legal system. The business manager needs a basic understanding of
the system when dealing with each liability claim. The American legal sys-
tem identifies unpaid liabilities as a harm to society, a breach of the social
contract. The civil law system3 provides opportunities for those harmed
to seek a remedy. Anyone seeking a remedy must tell the court which
sort of harm is claimed. These include torts—one party’s wrongful harm
to another, notwithstanding any business contract between them, and also
breach of contract—one party’s wrongful harm to another caused by failure
to uphold a business contract between them.
Torts are a catchall that covers almost every business liability other
than those specified in a business contract. Torts, each a harm inflicted
on society, include intentional harm, negligence, nuisance, and trespass,
and each works pretty much as its name suggests. A manufacturer that
foolishly uses the wrong screws to hold its product together, causing
injury to customers, commits negligence. An ageing paper mill that de-
cides to keep operating despite a broken fan system—thereby polluting
a nearby town—commits nuisance. If the mill’s staff crosses a farmer’s
land with heavy trucks, in a rush to fix the fans, they commit trespass.
Related to the idea of trespass is the wrongful taking or laying hold of
property, itself a tort.
The scope of torts is as broad as the sorts of harm that the courts intent
to remedy. For example, consider the general idea of property—anything
tangible or intangible that is owned by a person or an entity, and the right to
possess, keep, hold, use, enjoy, and dispose of what is owned. A farmer’s land
is property, but so is a special method that the farmer may have devised to
process his crop for delivery to market4—a form of intellectual property.
Claims of tort and contract breach are brought to a court, and if deemed
in good order will trigger a trial or other court-ordered proceeding. At the
3
Substantively, civil law means the set of laws concerning actions that are noncriminal
yet against society’s interests.
4
For example, this nation’s first president George Washington developed and im-
plemented improvements on the common sort of drill, plow, barn, and threshing
method in his days of farming.
Business Liability 11
trial’s end the court will rule on the claim, based on evidence presented by
the claimant and defendant legal teams. To make its ruling, the court will
weigh and interpret the evidence in light of existing law, and also in light
of existing court decisions and commentary on similar past cases—the
common law tradition.5
For torts and contracts, past cases form an important source of law.
The U.S. Constitution, and its 27 amendments, says nothing specifically
about torts or business contracts. This is because the framers of these
documents saw in the existing court system a sound means of addressing
these wrongs. For business liabilities, the claimant acts as plaintiff, bring-
ing the case to common law court, and the business is called to answer
in its defense.
Each U.S. state has had, since its inception, a common law court sys-
tem to deal with torts and contracts, and while states’ approaches to these
matters vary, the federal government has not found the discrepancies so
egregious as to impose a national standard or code.6 It has, however, sup-
planted state courts with a system of federal courts. The decisions of both
state and federal courts can be challenged by the litigants (plaintiff and
defense teams), with appeal to the corresponding appellate court. If un-
satisfied there, litigants can further appeal to the corresponding supreme
court—state or federal. Some state supreme court cases can be appealed
to the federal supreme court.
A legal liability is any situation, identified by law, where an individ-
ual, a group, or an organization is found to bear obligation to another.
A business’s legal liability is then any situation, identified by law, where
a business is found to bear obligation to an individual, a group, or an
organization. To try a liability claim, the court often spends a lot of
5
Common law, manifest operationally as a civil procedure, relies on the court’s current
and past actions to determine case outcomes. This contrasts with the civil law proce-
dure in which the judge relies on written laws—rules and statutes—rather than on
past case decisions. In practice, the U.S. legal system’s procedures permit judges some
latitude in their use of statute versus precedent.
6
A model code of torts and contracts has been developed by the American Law
Institute—a group of legal scholars, lawyers, and judges, over the last 90 years, and is
sometimes cited in court decisions.
12 BUSINESS LIABILITY AND ECONOMIC DAMAGES
time dealing with evidence and protocol, and must complete the chal-
lenging task of interpreting liability in terms consistent with the will
of Congress and the court’s prior opinions. Legal teams, for plaintiff
and defense, know that judges look to laws (statutes) and past court
opinions (precedent) to decide matters, and so they research statutes
and precedents as they prepare their cases. Legal research, preparation
of evidence, and performance in court are all costly for the legal teams,
and so costly for their clients.
A bench trial—a trial with a judge and no jury—is work for the court,
a jury trial is more so. The jury examines evidence but knows little of rele-
vant statutes, legal precedent, or court procedure. The judge must instruct
the jury so that their opinion, or findings, reflects the logic of the relevant
law. If it does, then the judge’s decision, or holding, generally agrees with
the jury’s findings, otherwise not.
Our legal system is an expensive way to deal with business liability
claims. It is cheaper to settle a case before it reaches trial. In economic
terms, the claimant should accept any negotiated offer that leaves them
with more money than they would get by going through the court sys-
tem. The profit-minded business sued for liability should never make
an offer that leaves the claimant much better off than they would be
if they went through the court system, since a lower offer would still
keep the lawsuit out of the courts. The same maxim holds for the busi-
ness’s insurer.
The relatively few business liability cases that end up in court do so
because the claimant anticipates a higher net gain from going to trial than
any settlement offer they have received from the business or its insurer.
Knowing how costly trials are, the business should prefer instead to raise
the settlement offer above the threshold value that induces settlement,
unless the business believes that the claimant’s expected trial outcome is
too optimistic. In a simplified economic world where everybody holds
the same expectations about what will happen, no business liability case
would go to trial!
Substantial differences in expectations, which bring business liability
cases to trial, can reflect differences in the information held by plaintiff
Business Liability 13
and defense teams. However, the court’s rules of discovery usually serve
to expose secrets and minimize differences in information. The teams
might also have different opinions about the legal merits of the posi-
tions advanced by each side, or how these positions will be received by
the court. This can happen, for example, if the defense lawyer has lots of
experience with the judge and court at hand, while the plaintiff lawyer
does not.7
For business liability claims that do not get settled immediately, the
threat of a costly lawsuit often looms above further negotiations, but
cheaper forms of dispute resolution exist. Mediation—dispute resolution
facilitated by a neutral nonbinding third party—is relatively quick and pro-
cedurally simple. For business liability mediation to be useful, the busi-
ness and its liability claimant must have different expectations about the
mediation outcome; otherwise their common ground would beg settle-
ment beforehand. Successful mediation leads to discovery of evidence
that establishes common ground, so ending the dispute. The same holds
true of a court trial, but the court’s decision is binding. Between these two
forms of dispute resolution is arbitration—dispute resolution facilitated by
a neutral binding third party, cheaper than a trial and sometimes built into
contracts as a required substitute for trials.
Example
In this book we will explore a range of business liability examples, some
more complex than others. As a simple starting point, consider a hypo-
thetical company called Rent that rents trailers to construction compa-
nies. Rent does business in the Midwest and leases all its trailers from a
national manufacturer called Best, with each trailer leased for 5 years.
7
For liability cases that go to trial, a bench trial is quicker and less costly than a jury
trial, and carries more uncertainty. To prefer a jury trial, the plaintiff or defense must
expect that the jury’s findings will deviate favorably from what the judge’s holding
would be in a bench trial, yet not so much as to cause the judge to set aside the
findings.
14 BUSINESS LIABILITY AND ECONOMIC DAMAGES
Over time, Rent gets more and more trailers from Best, but then finds a
better deal from a local manufacturer. Rent returns all the Best trailers,
most of which have time left on their 5-year leases. The lease contract al-
lows such a return, but specifies that all unpaid installments on the trailers
are due at the time of return. Rent pays none of these future installments,
and so faces a business liability claim equal to the total of all unpaid future
installments; suppose this is $500,000.
Best, having a half million dollar claim against Rent, tries to collect. If
it has some other form of business engagement or contract with Rent, it
may try to prompt payment by business retaliation, or a threat of retalia-
tion. If no such “stick” is in its arsenal, Best will consider filing a lawsuit
against Rent, a costly undertaking that will hopefully still net Best a good
share of the claimed half million. Contract law provides this opportu-
nity via a claim of contract breach. There is some uncertainty about the
lawsuit’s outcome: Will the judge find it reasonable that payment for all
future (but void) rental periods was actually due at the time of the rental
property’s return? Will Best collect interest on the debt, and if so at what
interest rate?
In this deadbeat renter dispute there is an economic principle—
the time value of money—that can help the court decide the outcome.
According to this principle, there is usually an advantage to receiving
money earlier rather than later, and so the payment of all rent at once
leaves the renter in worse shape (and the rental company in better shape)
than if rent had been paid on its regular schedule. The value of this extra
advantage depends on market rates of interest and can be estimated. The
court might hold that the deadbeat renter pay its due without paying
the “extra,” or not, depending on the wording of the contract.
This simple example illustrates business liability, with some uncer-
tainty and economics involved, but the liability itself is predictable—a
company bails on a rental contract, thereby triggering a liability claim for
unpaid rent. In the remainder of this book, I focus more on economic
damages that arise in liability cases where the liability claim itself is not
so easy to predict. Such cases include personal injury, wrongful death,
wrongful termination, and intellectual property loss.
Business Liability 15
Exercises
• a one-time purchase,
• that is owned forever,
• allows for simultaneous readers,
• has no restrictions on printing, and
• can be downloaded as PDFs from within the library community.
Our digital library collections are a great solution to beat the rising cost of textbooks. E-books
can be loaded into their course management systems or onto students’ e-book readers.
The Business Expert Press digital libraries are very affordable, with no obligation to buy in
future years. For more information, please visit www.businessexpertpress.com/librarians.
To set up a trial in the United States, please email sales@businessexpertpress.com.